Pages

Monday, 16 November 2009

Inflation has no effect on the real value on non-monetary items

A house is a variable real value non-monetary item. Let us assume a house in Port Elizabeth is fairly valued in the PE market at say R 2 million on 1st January in year one. With no change in the market a year later but with inflation at 6% in SA, the seller would increase his or her price to R2.12 million - all else being equal. The house’s real value remained the same. The depreciating monetary price for the house expressed in the depreciating Rand medium of exchange – all else being equal - was inflation-adjusted to compensate for the destruction of the real value of the depreciating Rand in the internal SA market by 6% annual inflation. It is clear that inflation does not affect the house’s variable non-monetary real value – all else being equal.

However much inflation rises, it can only make the Rand more worthless at a higher rate and over a shorter period of time. Heaven forbid that what happened in Zimbabwe recently would ever happen in SA. As inflation rises the price of the house would rise to keep pace with inflation or value destruction in the real value of the Rand – all else being equal. The real value of the property will be updated as long as the house is valued as a variable real value non-monetary item at its market price, a measurement base dictated by IFRS and also practiced in all open markets.

When a property was valued at Historical Cost in the not so distant past in a company’s balance sheet it may have stayed at its original HC of, for example, R 100 000 for 28 years since January, 1981 in the company’s balance sheet. When it is eventually sold today for R 1.4 million we can see that inflation did not destroy the property’s variable real non-monetary value – all else being equal. Inflation only destroyed the real value of the depreciating Rand, the depreciating monetary medium of exchange, over the 28 year period - all else being equal. This was taken into account by the buyer and seller at the time of the sale. The selling price in Rand was increased to compensate for the destruction of the real value of the Rand by inflation. R1.4 million today (2009) is the same as R100 000 in January, 1981 – all else being equal.

As the two lady academics from Turkey state: Purchasing power of non monetary items does not change in spite of variation in national currency value.

Kindest regards,

Nicolaas Smith

Friday, 13 November 2009

First Zimbabwe. Now Venezuela. Next Malema and South Africa?

Hi,

Chavez´s nationalization continues.

26% annual inflation for 3 years in a row is hyperinflation.

Venezuela is already at 27% annual inflation.

Zimbabwe can guarantee Venezuela that price controls do not work.

As soon as price controls enter, production drops.

Robert Mugabe tried what no-one has ever done: beat the market.

Now Hugo Chavez is trying the same impossible dream: to beat the market.

He will also fail as Mugabe failed.

The market rules.

After Zimbabwe we can now watch Venezuela self-destruct.

I hope the ANC, Julius Malema, the ANCYL, Cosatu, Numsa and the SA Communist Party take careful note how this process unfolds because it always works exactly the same way. Go and look up the exact same process in Zimbabwe a year or two ago.

I see Venezuela already had 39% inflation at the end of last year. And a parallel USDollar exchange rate considerably higher than the "official" rate. And a local petrol price not increased for 10 years.

lol Exactly the same as hyperinflation in Angola and Zimbabwe.

Malema should take a sebatical year from politics in SA and go and learn again from Chavez how the above measures destroy a country´s economy in few short years.

I watched this exact same process unfold on a daily basis in Zimbabwe over the last two years. Venezuela is exactly the same. The same measures by government and the same characteristics in the economy.

Julius Malema can get first hand experience from Chavez how to destroy a country through trying unsuccessfully to surpress the market.

It is time to start reading a Venezuelan English online newspaper on a daily basis. Zimbabwe all over again. What a joke. Very interesting completely up to date daily economics though.

Kindest regards,

Nicolaas Smith

Thursday, 12 November 2009

Valuing fixed properties at HC before they are sold does not destroy their real values

The real values of fixed properties are not destroyed by SA accountants when they value these fixed assets at their original nominal HC values before the date that they are actually exchanged during low inflation. They would be valued at their current market values on the date of exchange in an open economy. During hyperinflation all variable items are required to be valued in units of constant purchasing power with reference to the CPI or a hard currency parallel rate – normally the US Dollar parallel rate.

This is not the case with reported constant items never maintained under the HC paradigm. Accountants unknowingly destroy the real values of reported constant items never maintained at a rate equal to the rate of inflation in a low inflationary environment with their stable measuring unit assumption under HCA.

Variable items´ real values are not being unknowingly destroyed by SA accountants as a result of their implementation of IFRS or SA GAAP since variable items exist independently of how we value them. They can value a variable item in the balance sheet at its HC 50 years ago, but, when it is sold in the market today, the variable item would be transacted at the current market price. The real values of variable items are also not being destroyed uniformly at, e.g., a rate equal to the inflation rate because of valuing them at original nominal HC. Inflation, per se, has no effect on the real values of variable items on a primary valuation basis.

Where real losses are made in dealing with variable items in SA, these losses are the result of supply and demand or business and private decisions, e.g. selling at a bad price, obsolescence, stock market crashes, credit crunches, etc. They do not result from the implementation by SA accountants of the HC accounting model.

Kindest regards,

Nicolaas Smith

Tuesday, 10 November 2009

The Historical Cost Debate

Originally – before there were any GAAPs and IFRSs – all variable items as well as all constant items together with all monetary items (basically all items in financial statements) were valued at Historical Cost since money – the monetary unit of account –was generally assumed to be stable in real value over time: the infamous stable measuring unit assumption. Today, SA accountants maintain this infamous and very destructive and very economically destabilizing assumption only for the valuation of the majority of income statement items (excluding salaries, wages, rents, etc that accountants value in units of constant purchasing power) and all balance sheet constant items during low inflation and deflation.

Values used in relation to variable items include the following:

Market value
Fair value
Net realisable value
Present value
Recoverable value
Current cost
Carrying value

Residual value

“The residual value of an asset is the estimated amount that an entity would currently obtain from disposal of the asset, after deducting the estimated costs of disposal, if the asset were already of the age and in the condition expected at the end of its useful life.”

Value in use
Settlement value
Book value
Replacement cost
Historical cost

The Historical Cost Debate

The Historical Cost Debate is the debate over the last 100 years or so about the exclusive use of Historical Cost for all accounting purposes. The accounting profession has realized for a very long time that financial reports based on Historical Cost for all economic items do not fairly represent a company’s results and operations. As a result of this debate the pure Historical Cost Accounting model has been improved dramatically during this time, so much so, that today we have a huge volume of IFRS where under variable items are not all valued at HC but at the values as indicated above. As a result of the Historical Cost Debate variable items are today valued at, e.g. fair value or the lower of cost and net realizable value or market value or recoverable value or present value. This debate has thus been a very valid and successful debate regarding the valuation of variable real value non-monetary items.

Unfortunately, the stable measuring unit assumption is still an IFRS compliant option that everyone uses for the valuation of most constant items during low inflation and deflation. Fortunately, the option of measuring financial capital maintenance in units of constant purchasing power during low inflation has been approved by the IASB in the Framework, Par. 104 (a) in 1989. Unfortunately, no-one uses it.

SA accountants value variable items in terms of IFRSs or SA GAAP when they implement both the traditional HCA model and whenever they decide to choose to measure financial capital maintenance in units of constant purchasing power. Inflation, per se, has no effect on the real values of variable items. Inflation – per se – can only destroy the real value of money and other monetary items: nothing else.

Kindest regards,

Nicolaas Smith

Monday, 9 November 2009

Variable items exist independently of how accountants value them

As we know, the economy consists of three basic economic items:

1.Monetary items
2.Variable real value non-monetary items
3.Constant real value non-monetary items

Monetary items are money held and items with an underlying monetary nature. Non-monetary items are all items that are not monetary items. Non-monetary items are further sub-divided into variable and constant items.

Variable items are non-monetary items with variable real values
valued in terms of IFRS or GAAP.

The first economic items were variable items not yet expressed in terms of money since money was not yet invented at that time. Once money was invented all economic items, including variable items, were expressed in monetary terms.

Examples of variable items and how they are valued

Property – at cost or fair value
Freehold Land – at cost or fair value
Buildings – at cost or fair value
Leasehold Improvements – at cost
Plant – at cost
Equipment – at cost
Equipment under Finance Lease – at cost
Investment Property – at fair value
Goodwill – at cost
Other Intangible Assets – at cost
Capitalised Development Items – at cost
Patents – at cost
Trademarks – at cost
Licences – at cost
Investments in Associates – at cost
Joint Ventures – at cost
Other Financial Assets – at fair value
Derivatives designated and effective as hedging instruments – at fair value
Foreign currency forward contracts – at fair value
Interest rate swaps – at fair value
Financial assets carried at fair value through profit or loss
Non-derivative financial assets designated as carried at fair value through profit or loss
Held for trading derivatives that are not designated in hedge accounting relationships – at fair value
Held for trading non-derivative financial assets – at fair value
Available-for-sale investments carried at fair value
Redeemable notes – at fair value
Shares – at fair value
Inventories – at the lower of cost and net realisable value
Raw Materials – at the lower of cost and net realisable value
Work-in-progress – at the lower of cost and net realisable value
Finished Goods – at the lower of cost and net realisable value
Foreign currency – at market value

Variable items in South Africa are valued, for example, at fair value or the lower of cost and net realizable value or recoverable value or market value or present value in terms of IFRS or SA GAAP. “Listed companies use IFRS and the unlisted companies could use either IFRS or Statements of GAAP.”

SA financial reports fairly represent the fundamental real values of variable items in terms of IFRS or SA GAAP only at the balance sheet date – excluding those valued at original nominal Historical Cost when that original date is not the balance sheet date on a primary valuation basis. The fundamental real values of variable items exist independently of being valued at their original nominal HC after the original date they came about or were acquired by the firm. Valuing a variable item at its original nominal HC during its lifetime does not destroy its real value because it will be valued at its current market value whenever it is finally exchanged or sold or disposed of in the future.

© 2005-2010 by Nicolaas J Smith. All rights reserved

No reproduction without permission.

Wednesday, 4 November 2009

Measurement of the Elements of Financial Statements

Here is a verbatim copy of some paragraphs of the International Accounting Standard Board´s


Framework for the Preparation and Presentation of Financial Statements (1989)



Measurement of the Elements of Financial Statements

Par. 99. Measurement is the process of determining the monetary amounts at which the elements of the financial statements are to be recognised and carried in the balance sheet and income statement. This involves the selection of the particular basis of measurement.

Par. 100. A number of different measurement bases are employed to different degrees and in varying combinations in financial statements. They include the following:

(a) Historical cost. Assets are recorded at the amount of cash or cash equivalents paid or the fair value of the consideration given to acquire them at the time of their acquisition. Liabilities are recorded at the amount of proceeds received in exchange for the obligation, or in some circumstances (for example, income taxes), at the amounts of cash or cash equivalents expected to be paid to satisfy the liability in the normal course of business.

(b) Current cost. Assets are carried at the amount of cash or cash equivalents that would have to be paid if the same or an equivalent asset was acquired currently. Liabilities are carried at the undiscounted amount of cash or cash equivalents that would be required to settle the obligation currently.

(c) Realisable (settlement) value. Assets are carried at the amount of cash or cash equivalents that could currently be obtained by selling the asset in an orderly disposal. Liabilities are carried at their settlement values; that is, the undiscounted amounts of cash or cash equivalents expected to be paid to satisfy the liabilities in the normal course of business.

(d) Present value. Assets are carried at the present discounted value of the future net cash inflows that the item is expected to generate in the normal course of business. Liabilities are carried at the present discounted value of the future net cash outflows that are expected to be required to settle the liabilities in the normal course of business.

Par. 101. The measurement basis most commonly adopted by entities in preparing their financial statements is historical cost. This is usually combined with other measurement bases. For example, inventories are usually carried at the lower of cost and net realisable value, marketable securities may be carried at market value and pension liabilities are carried at their present value. Furthermore, some entities use the current cost basis as a response to the inability of the historical cost accounting model to deal with the effects of changing prices of non-monetary assets.




The above sections of the Framework do not include measurement in units of constant purchasing power. This comes next in the concept of capital and the concept of capital maintenance in the Framework. It is an actual measurement basis. It is the measurement basis currently used by all accountants worldwide - including SA accountants - to value salaries, wages, rentals, regulated prices, etc in units of constant purchasing power during low inflation. It is thus universally used for the valuation of only some income statement constant real value non-monetary items during low inflation.

It is required to be used for all non-monetary items - variable and constant real value non-monetary items - during hyperinflation. This is a requirement of IAS 29 Financial Reporting in Hyperinflationary Economies.

It is also required by the IASB to be used for the valuation of all income statement and balance sheet constant items during low inflation when accountants choose financial capital maintenance in units of constant purchasing power in terms of the Framework, Par. 104 (a) during low inflation.

Measurement in units of constant purchasing power is thus completely generally accepted as a distinct and well understood and universally used measurement basis during low inflation. It is a generally accepted accounting principle (GAAP) during low, high and hyperinflation.


See the IASB deliberations regarding MEASUREMENT as of October 2014


Buy the ebook

Nicolaas Smith Copyright (c) 2005-2014 Nicolaas J Smith. All rights reserved. No reproduction without permission.

Tuesday, 3 November 2009

The net monetary gain or loss conundrum

SA accountants have to calculate the net monetary loss or gain from holding monetary items when they choose the Constant ITEM Purchasing Power Accounting model in terms of the International Accounting Standards Board´s Framework, Par. 104 (a) and measure financial capital maintenance in units of constant purchasing power in the same way as the IASB currently in terms of IAS 29 requires its calculation and accounting during hyperinflation.

There are net monetary losses and net monetary gains during low inflation too, but they are not required to be calculated when accountants choose the traditional Historical Cost Accounting model.

It is an inexplicable contradiction that net monetary gains and losses are required by the IASB to be calculated and accounted during hyperinflation but not during non-hyperinflationary periods, especially when the IASB approved alternative to HCA, namely CIPPA does require their calculation and accounting during low inflation.

Kindest regards,

Nicolaas Smith

Monday, 2 November 2009

Ultimately, inflation-adjusting accounts in a low inflation environment is a blessing to users.

The statement "Financial capital maintenance can be measured in either nominal monetary units or units of constant purchasing power," in the IASB´s Framework, Paragraph 104 (a), means that Constant ITEM Purchasing Power Accounting has been authorized by the IASB since 1989 as an alternative to the traditional HCA model, including during periods of low inflation.

This means that the international accounting profession has been in agreement regarding the use of CIPPA for financial capital maintenance in units of CPP during low inflation since 1989. It also means that CIPPA and the inflation-adjustment of constant items to maintain their real values in a low inflationary environment are authorized by IFRS since the Framework is applicable in the absence of specific IFRS.

Income statement constant items like salaries, wages, rents, pensions, utilities, transport fees, etc are normally valued by accountants in units of CPP during low inflation in most economies. Payments in money for these items are normally inflation-adjusted by means of the CPI to compensate for the destruction of the real value of money (the monetary medium of exchange) by inflation.

Inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon and can only destroy the real value of money (the functional currency inside an economy) and other monetary items. Inflation can not and does not destroy the real value of non-monetary items. Constant items´ real values can be maintained by accountants choosing the CIPPA model as per the Framework during low inflation as authorized by the IASB since 1989 instead of currently being destroyed by the implementation by accountants of the traditional HC model when they apply the stable measuring unit assumption.

It is thus accountants´ choice of the HCA model and not inflation that destroys the real value of constant items never maintained at a rate equal to the inflation rate when HC accountants choose to implement the stable measuring unit assumption for an indefinite period of time during continuous inflation.

Implementing the CIPPA model means accountants choose to reject the stable measuring unit assumption which they implement when they choose to measure financial capital maintenance in nominal monetary units. Accountants world wide currently choose the traditional HCA model except during hyperinflation when they are required by the IASB to implement IAS 29 which is based on the CPPA inflation accounting model.

Kindest regards,

Nicolaas Smith

Friday, 30 October 2009

Hyperinflation in South Africa

IFRS compliant financial capital maintenance in units of constant purchasing power would always be a better accounting model than HCA during inflation.

SA accountants unknowingly destroy the real value of reported Retained Earnings at the rate of inflation under HCA implementing the stable measuring unit assumption in the SA real economy.

Rejecting the stable measuring unit assumption by measuring financial capital maintenance in units of constant purchasing power as authorized by the IASB in the Framework, Par. 104 (a) in 1989 would stop this destruction of real value in Retained Earnings.

It would remove distortions in the real economy, improve economic stability and guarantee that no wipe-out of internal demand would be possible in the SA economy like what happened in the recent past in the Zimbabwean economy under very high rates of inflation.

Hyperinflation is still possible in SA in the Rand, but, with no stable measuring unit assumption and all constant items (including salaries, wages, rentals, shareholders´ equity, trade debtors, trade creditors, taxes payable, taxes receivable, etc) being automatically updated in units of constant purchasing power, economic stability in the real economy would be guaranteed as it was in Brazil during 30 years of hyperinflation of up to 2000% per annum.

Brazil used indexation to maintain the real values of non-monetary items during the 30 years of hyperinflation in their internal currencies during that period.

Financial capital maintenance in units of constant purchasing power in terms of the Framework, Par. 104 (a), is the same as indexation, but, only in constant items - not in variable real value non-monetary items. The latter are valued in terms of IFRS or SA GAAP.

Retained Earnings can be updated under IFRS but not under HCA.

Kindest regards,

Nicolaas Smith

How to maintain your capital

The specific choice of measuring financial capital maintenance in units of constant purchasing power (the Constant Item Purchasing Power Accounting model) during non-hyperinflationary periods as contained in the Framework, Par. 104 (a) , was approved by the IASB’s predecessor body, the International Accounting Standards Committee Board, in April 1989 for publication in July 1989 and adopted by the IASB in April 2001.

Deloitte

“In the absence of a Standard or an Interpretation that specifically applies to a transaction, management must use its judgement in developing and applying an accounting policy that results in information that is relevant and reliable. In making that judgement, IAS 8.11 requires management to consider the definitions, recognition criteria, and measurement concepts for assets, liabilities, income, and expenses in the Framework. This elevation of the importance of the Framework was added in the 2003 revisions to IAS 8."

IAS8, 11:

“In making the judgement, management shall refer to, and consider the applicability of, the following sources in descending order:

(a) the requirements and guidance in Standards and Interpretations dealing with similar and related issues; and

(b) the definitions, recognition criteria and measurement concepts for assets, liabilities, income and expenses in the Framework.”

There is no applicable IFRS or Interpretation regarding the capital concept, the capital maintenance concept and the valuation of constant items. The Framework is thus applicable.

Despite being applicable as a result of the absence of specific IFRS CIPPA is completely ignored by accountants and accounting authorities even though they would maintain the real value of constant items with it instead of currently unknowingly destroying the real values of not only all income statement constant items but also all balance sheet constant items never maintained when they implement the traditional HCA model.

This is because the CIPPA model is mistakenly viewed by almost all accountants and accounting authorities, but excluding the IASB, as the same as the 1970-style failed CPPA inflation accounting model that requires all non-monetary items - variable and constant items - to be inflation-adjusted by means of the CPI. They - including the IASB - fail to introduce the substantial real value maintaining benefits, which last for an unlimited period of time (all else being equal), of measuring financial capital maintenance in units of CPP in companies and the economy in general.

The IASB did not approve CIPPA in 1989 as an inflation accounting model. It did that with CPPA in IAS29. CIPPA by measuring financial capital maintenance in units of CPP incorporates an alternative CPP capital concept, CPP financial capital maintenance concept and CPP profit determination concept to the HC capital concept, HC financial capital maintenance concept and HC profit determination concept. CIPPA only requires all constant items to be valued in units of CPP. Variable items are valued in terms of IFRS or GAAP and are not required in terms of the Framework to be valued in units of CPP.

© 2005-2010 by Nicolaas J Smith. All rights reserved

No reproduction without permission.

Wednesday, 28 October 2009

Trust me, I´m an accountant

SA accountants unknowingly destroy the real value of your company’s equity since they assume there´s no inflation.

They unknowingly destroy the real value of Retained Profits with their stable measuring unit assumption, but, they also do not update the cost of inventories and cost of sales.

Consequently they overstate gross margins and instead of maintaining the full real value of equity, they pay some of it away in tax on inflation-adjustments, they fail to update trade debtors and they can also pay it away in dividends.

Kindest regards,

Nicolaas Smith

Monday, 26 October 2009

The IASB´s alternative to Historical Cost Accounting

The IASB´s alternative to Historical Cost Accounting


Buy the ebook 



Last updated on 17 April, 2012

Constant Purchasing Power Accounting (CPPA) as defined in International Accounting Standard IAS 29 Financial Reporting in Hyperinflationary Economies is the International Accounting Standards Board´s inflation accounting model required to be implemented only during hyperinflation.

Constant ITEM Purchasing Power Accounting (CIPPA) is the IASB´s basic accounting alternative to traditional Historical Cost Accounting during low and high inflation and deflation. The stable measuring unit assumption is implemented under HCA. The stable measuring unit assumption is never implemented as a GAAP under CIPPA. HCA implements financial capital maintenance in nominal monetary units. CIPPA implements financial capital maintenance in units of constant purchasing power in terms of a daily index. CIPPA is fundamentally different from HCA. Financial capital maintenance in nominal monetary units is a fallacy because if is impossible to maintain the constant purchasing power (real value) of capital constant in nominal monetary units per se during inflation and deflation. CIPPA, on the other hand, automatically maintains the constant purchasing power of capital constant for an indefinite period of time in all entities that at least break even in real value at all levels of inflation and deflation - ceteris paribus.

Both CPPA and CIPPA are price-level accounting models. IAS 29 simply requires the restatement of all non-monetary items (both variable and constant real value non-monetary items) in Historical Cost or Current Cost period-end financial statements in terms of the period-end monthly published Consumer Price Index during hyperinflation. IAS 29 is an extension to, not a departure from HCA per PricewaterhouseCoopers. IAS 29 had no effect during hyperinflation in Zimbabwe.

CIPPA as approved by the IASB in the original Framework for the Preparation and Presentation of Financial Statements (1989), Par. 104 (a) which states

'Financial capital maintenance can be measured in either nominal monetary units or units of constant purchasing power'

requires the following:

(1) Daily inflation-adjustement of all historic and current period monetary items in terms of a Daily CPI or monetized daily indexed unit of account. The net monetary loss or gain is calculated and accounted when monetary items are not inflation-adjusted daily during the current accounting periõd. The net monetary loss or gain is a constant real value non-monetary item once accounted in the income statement.
(2) Daily valuation of variable real value non-monetary items in terms of IFRS excluding the stable measuring unit assumption. Historical variable items (e.g., valued yesterday) are updated daily in terms of the Daily CPI or monetized daily indexed unit of account when they are not valued daily in terms of IFRS during low and high inflation and deflation. Impairments are treated in terms of IFRS.

(3) Historic and current period constant items are always and everywhere measured in units of constant purchasing power in terms of the Daily CPI or monetized daily indexed unit of account during low and high inflation and deflation. The net constant item loss or gain is calculated and accounted when current period constant items are not measured daily in units of constant purchasing power.

In terms of the Framework, accountants can choose CIPPA to implement a financial capital concept of invested purchasing power instead of the traditional HC concept of invested money. They will thus implement a CPP financial capital maintenance concept by measuring financial capital maintenance in units of CPP instead of traditional HC nominal monetary units and they will implement a CPP profit/loss determination concept. Examples of constant items include issued share capital, retained income, shareholders´ equity, trade debtors, trade creditors, deferred tax assets and liabilities, salaries, wages, rentals, etc. Examples of variable item include property, plant, equipment, shares, inventory.

Monetary, variable and constant items are the three fundamentally different basic economic items in the economy.

CIPPA would maintain the real value of constant items including banks´ and companies´ capital base, for an unlimited period of time - all else being equal, as opposed to the traditional HCA model which unknowingly, unintentionally and unnecessarily erode the real value of constant items never maintained constant. CIPPA was authorized by the IASB in 1989 as an alternative to the traditional HCA model at all levels of inflation and deflation in the Framework and is applicable as a result of the absence of specific IFRS relating to the concepts of capital and capital maintenance and the valuation of constant items.

CIPPA (not CPPA) during hyperinflation would be the same as in non-hyperinflationary economies. The only difference is that the daily rate would be a relatively stable foreign currency daily parallel rate (normally the US Dollar daily parallel rate) or a Brazilian-style Unidade Real de Valor daily index rate. All non-monetary items (variable and constant items) would be measured in units of constant purchasing power on a daily basis as indicated above during hyperinflation.

Discredited 1970-style CPPA was a form of inflation accounting which tried unsuccessfully - by updating all non-monetary items (variable and constant items) equally by means of the CPI during high inflation - to allow for the effect of the stable measuring unit assumption in an attempt to make corporate accounts more informative when comparing current transactions with previous transactions.

Nevertheless, almost all accountants and accounting authorities - excluding the IASB - mistakenly regard CIPPA as the same as the discredited and failed 1970-style CPPA inflation accounting model. They ignore the CIPPA model's substantial benefits, for example, automatically maintaining banks´ and companies´ capital base when accountants choose to measure constant items in units of constant purchasing power by means of the Daily CPI thus maintaining instead of continuously eroding their real values at a rate equal to the rate of inflation while they value variable items daily in terms of IFRS or GAAP excluding the stable measuring unit assumption.

Certain income statement constant items, most notably salaries, wages and rentals, etc. are measured in units of constant purchasing power on an annual basis, but are paid in fixed monthly amounts again implementing the stable measuring unit assumption in most economies implementing the HCA model.

The IASB specifically requires the CPPA inflation accounting model to be used during hyperinflation as per IAS 29.


Buy the ebook for $2.99 or £1.53 or €2.68
Nicolaas Smith

Copyright (c) 2005-2012 Nicolaas J Smith. All rights reserved. No reproduction without permission.

Friday, 23 October 2009

A 45% electricity price increase should not increase inflation - in theory.

A price increase is paying more money for more real value.

Inflation is paying of more money for the same real value.

In theory, when electricity becomes more valuable in the SA economy and it´s price is increased by 45%, then households would have to spend less on other items – all else being equal.

Thus, no increase or decrease in inflation.

Inflation comes about when business abuses the electricity price increase to increase the general price level instead of just the price of electricity.

A one percent increase in inflation – paying one per cent more for the same real value in general – is expected as a result of the electricity price increase.

A 45% price increase for three years in a row equals a 304% increase over that period.

Kindest regards,

Nicolaas Smith

Wednesday, 21 October 2009

Valuing monetary items during low inflation

Valuing monetary items during low inflation

Money and other monetary items can not be updated or indexed or inflation-adjusted or maintained during the current financial period under any accounting model under any economic mode that is not sustainable zero per cent annual inflation. Inflation destroys the real value of monetary items evenly throughout the SA monetary economy currently at 6.4% per annum (Aug 2009) or about R124 billion per annum. Monetary items only maintain their real values perfectly stable under sustainable zero per cent annual inflation. This has never been achieved before over an extended period of time.

The South African Reserve Bank conducts monetary policy within an inflation targeting framework. The current target is for CPI inflation to be within the target range of 3 to 6 per cent on a continuous basis. SARB

The SARB´s definition of price stability, in practice, is the destruction of the real value of the Rand at a rate of 6% or about R120 billion per annum because inflation normally increases to the top of the inflation targeting range. Real value is destroyed evenly in Rand bank notes and coins and other monetary items (loans, deposits, etc) throughout the SA monetary economy. Why destroying R120 billion per annum of the Rand´s real value in people’s pockets is supposedly good for the SA economy – supposedly good for economic growth and supposedly good for creating employment – is not well known in the SA economy.

SA accountants account monetary items at their original nominal values – at their historical cost – during the current financial period. It thus appears that it is correct when it is stated that “financial reporting simply reports on what took place”. That is dead wrong. Accountants value everything they account. There is no other way monetary items can be accounted and valued during the current financial period. It is an illusion that accountants only record what happened in the past: the “financial reporting simply reports on what took place” illusion as promoted by some SA accounting professors.

SA accountants value monetary items at their current depreciated generally lower real values by accounting them at their original nominal values during inflation. Their real values are destroyed by inflation over time. Being stated at their original nominal values by accountants during inflation means that monetary items are automatically being valued by the continuous economic process of inflation over time.

This obviously means that monetary items are always correctly valued during the current financial period in any current account: at the current real value as determined by the current rate of inflation. Money and other monetary items´ real values consequently generally decrease monthly to a lower real value in low inflationary economies.

SA accountants do not destroy the real value of monetary items in the SA monetary economy: inflation does that. SA accountants value and account monetary items correctly in the SA monetary economy by stating them at their original nominal values. They, however, fail to calculate and account the net monetary gains and losses from holding either net monetary liabilities or net monetary assets, as the case may be.

The only difference between accounting and valuing monetary items under the current real value destroying Historical Cost Accounting model and their accounting and valuation when measuring financial capital maintenance in real value maintaining units of constant purchasing power would be the calculation and accounting of net monetary gains and losses. These gains and losses are not calculated and accounted under the HCA model although it can be done. See Kapnick above. No-one does that under HCA. Net monetary gains and losses are constant real value non-monetary items (income statement gains and losses) once they are accounted and have to be inflation-adjusted thereafter under the Constant ITEM Purchasing Power Accounting model.

© 2005-2010 by Nicolaas J Smith. All rights reserved

No reproduction without permission

Accountants transform an illusion into a GAAP

Inflation destroys the assumption that money is stable which is the basis of classic accountancy. In such circumstances, historical values registered in accountancy books become heterogeneous amounts measured in different units. The use of such data under traditional accounting methods without previous correction makes no sense and leads to results that are void of meaning.

Massone, 1981a. p.6

Money’s third function is that it is the unit of account in the economy. It is a monetary standard of measure of the real value of economic items to facilitate exchange without barter in order to overcome the double coincidence of wants problem. Inflation destroys the real value of money and deflation increases the real value of money. Money has never been perfectly stable in real value over an extended period of time. However, money illusion makes people believe that money maintains its real value over the short to medium term. Money is the only standard unit of measure that is not a fundamentally stable or fixed unit of value. All other standards of measure are perfectly stable units.

Accountants transformed money illusion into an official generally accepted accounting principle with their stable measuring unit assumption, also called the Measuring Unit Principle.

The unit of measure in accounting shall be the base money unit of the most relevant currency. This principle also assumes the unit of measure is stable; that is, changes in its general purchasing power are not considered sufficiently important to require adjustments to the basic financial reports.


Kindest regards,

Nicolaas Smith

Tuesday, 20 October 2009

Inflation is the abuse of the Rand´s store of value function

Money is a store of value. Money is a depreciating store of value during inflation and an appreciating store of value during deflation.

Money has to maintain most of its value over time in order to be accepted as a medium of exchange. It would not solve barter’s double coincidence of wants problem if it could not be stored over time and still remain valuable in exchange.

The fact that inflation is destroying the real value of money means it is a store of depreciating real value during inflation. Money was a store of value right from the start. First types of money consisted of gold or silver coins. The metals from which the coins were made had an actual real value in themselves and these coins could be melted down and the metal could be sold in its bullion form when the bullion price was above the coin price. Next money was not made of precious metal coins but money consisted of bank notes, the real values of which were fully backed by gold reserves. Today depreciating money simply represents depreciating real value since depreciating bank notes and bank coins have no intrinsic value. Although the store of value function and nominal values of depreciating bank notes and bank coins are legally defined, their depreciating real values are determined by the economic process of inflation.

The abuse of money’s store of value function led to inflation.

Money is very liquid; i.e. it is readily available as cash and it is normally easy to obtain on demand. A property, e.g. a well-located plot of land with a well-maintained and well-equipped building is also a store of value. It is however quite an illiquid store of value. The real value is not immediately available in easily transportable and divisible cash. Money’s high liquidity makes it more desirable as a store of value in comparison with other stores of value like gold, property, marketable securities, bonds, etc. Money is obviously not the best store of value in an inflationary economy where its real value is being destroyed by inflation. Money is normally available in convenient smaller denominations which facilitate everyday small purchases. As such, money is very user friendly. It is easily transportable especially with electronic transfer facilities.

Inflation actually manifests itself in money’s store of value function. Inflation does not manifest itself in money’s medium of exchange function or unit of account functions which vindicates the fact that inflation can only destroy the real value of money and monetary items; i.e. inflation has no effect on the real value of non-monetary items. Money is always a medium of exchange of equal real value at the moment of exchange. Free market prices are adjusted in the market in a price setting process that takes the decreasing real value of money into account (amongst many other factors) so that economic items (the product and the amount of money) of equal real value are exchanged at the moment of exchange.

Constant real value non-monetary items, e.g. salaries, wages, rents, etc which are measured in units of constant purchasing power (inflation-adjusted)

Depreciating money has a constantly decreasing real value. Depreciating “bank money” deposits have the same attributes of depreciating money with the single exception that they are not physical depreciating bank notes and bank coins but accounted depreciating monetary values. The depreciating money represented by depreciating accounted bank money also has a depreciating store of value function.

A country’s money supply consists of banknotes and coins (currency) and bank money or demand deposits - the balances in savings and deposit accounts. Intangible bank money is usually a much larger part of the money supply than bank notes and coins.

SA monetary aggregates

According to the SARB the monetary aggregates in SA consist of the following:

M0

Deposits of banks and mutual banks with the SARB and notes and coins outside
the SARB and SA mint

M1A

Coins and banknotes in circulation outside the monetary sector, cheque and
transmission deposits with banking institutions and the post office savings
bank

M1

MIA plus other demand deposits with banking institutions

M2

M1 plus other short term deposits, and all medium term deposits (including
savings deposits) with the monetary banking institutions

M3

M2 plus all long term deposits with monetary banking institutions


In a low cash inflationary economy depreciating money is a store of decreasing real value but it is generally assumed to have a stable – as in fixed - real value. SA accountants officially assume that the Rand is perfectly stable when they value fixed balance sheet constant real value non-monetary items never maintained. They do not consider the destruction of the Rand´s real value (e.g. at 6.4% per annum and even up to more than 20% per annum, but not as high as 26% per annum for three years in a row) as sufficiently important for them to decide to measure constant items in units of constant purchasing power - as approved by the IASB twenty years ago - to stop the destruction of real value in fixed balance sheet constant items (issued share capital, retained profits, all other shareholders equity items, trade debtors, trade creditors, taxes payable, taxes receivable, etc) never maintained. SA accountants´ stable measuring unit assumption is very destructive and totally unacceptable. It always was and now still is fundamentally wrong and very costly to the SA economy. SA accountants unknowingly destroy about R200 billion in the real value of constant items never maintained in this manner – each and every year (all else being equal).

Kindest regards,

Nicolaas Smith

Monday, 19 October 2009

Eskom: 1% Increase in inflation will cost SA an additional R53 billion per annum

Fin24.Com: Power price hikes fuel inflation

2009/10/18 11:45:00 AM Sake24.com reporter

"Johannesburg - Eskom's proposed electricity price hike will increase inflation by between a half and one percentage point.

Econometrix chief economist Dr Azar Jammine said South Africa will be fortunate if inflation falls to within the Reserve Bank's target range for the consumer price index of 3% to 6%.

"Inflation may fall below 6% in the second quarter of next year, but after that it will climb to 7% and stay there," Jammine told the annual congress of the South African Chamber of Commerce and Industry (SACCI) in Johannesburg on Friday."




A one percent increase in inflation will cost SA an additional R53 billion per year:

(1) Inflation will destroy an additional R20 billion in the real value of the Rand each and every year there after.

(2) SA accountants will unknowingly (?) destroy an additional about R33 billion in the real value of constant items never maintained in the SA real economy - e.g. in Retained Earnings - with their very destructive stable measuring unit assumption.

This will carry on for as long as the additional 1% increase stays in place and SA accountants keep on refusing to measure financial capital maintenance in units of constant purchasing power as they have been authorized to do by the International Accounting Standards Board in the Framework, Par. 104 (a) twenty years ago.

Increases in the price level (inflation) destroy the real value of money (the functional currency) and other monetary items with an underlying monetary nature (e.g. loans and bonds). However, inflation has no effect on the real value of variable real value non-monetary items (e.g. goods and commodities, like cars, gold, real estate, inventories, finished goods, foreign exchange, etc) and constant real value non-monetary items (e.g. issued share capital, retained profits, capital reserves, salaries, wages, rentals, pensions, trade debtors, trade creditors, taxes payable, taxes receivable, deferred tax assets, deferred tax liabilities, etc).

SA accountants choose to implement the stable measuring unit assumption during low inflation when they value constant items in fixed nominal monetary units. SA accountants´ choice of implementing the stable measuring unit assumption instead of measuring constant items´ real values in units of constant purchasing power results in the real values of these fixed constant real value non-monetary items being destroyed at a rate equal to the rate of inflation when they are never maintained during low inflation because inflation destroys the real value of money which is the monetary measuring unit of account. Constant items are treated like monetary items when their real values are never maintained as a result of the implementation of the stable measuring unit assumption as part of the traditional Historical cost accounting model.

“The Measuring Unit principle: The unit of measure in accounting shall be the base money unit of the most relevant currency. This principle also assumes the unit of measure is stable; that is, changes in its general purchasing power are not considered sufficiently important to require adjustments to the basic financial statements.”

At 7% inflation the total real value destroyed in the SA economy would be:

R140 billion per annum by inflation in the real value of the Rand in the monetary economy.

R233 billion (estimate) unknowingly (?) destroyed by SA accountants in the real value of constant items never maintained in the SA non-monetary or real economy.

Total: R373 billion per annum

When SA accountants freely decide to measure financial capital maintenance in units of constant purchasing power as per the IASB´s Framework, Par. 104 (a), then the total annual destruction will be reduced from R373 billion to only R140 billion real value destruction by inflation in the real value of the Rand.

PS: Do you know an accountant?

© 2005-2010 by Nicolaas J Smith. All rights reserved

No reproduction without permission.

Sunday, 18 October 2009

Medium of Exchange

Money performs the following three functions:

1. Medium of exchange
2. Store of value
3. Unit of account

1. Medium of Exchange

Money has the basic function that it is a medium of exchange of equivalent real values at the moment of exchange. It overcomes the inconveniences of a barter economy where there must be a coincidence of wants before a trade can take place. For a trade to take place in a barter economy one person must want exactly what the other person has to offer, at the exact time and place where it is offered.

In a monetary economy the real value of goods and services are measured in terms of money, the monetary medium of exchange, which is generally accepted to buy any other good or service. Without this function or attribute the invention cannot be money.

We use payment with money instead of barter to exchange real values in our economies in the transactions we enter into when we buy and sell goods, services, ideas, rights and any kind of property whether physical, virtual or intellectual. Money is the lifeblood of an economy even though it is continuously changing in real value. Without money the creation and exchange of real value in an economy would be severely restricted, as it would become a barter economy.

Kindest regards,

Nicolaas Smith

Friday, 16 October 2009

Consumer Price Index

“The consumer price index was first used in 1707. In 1925 it became institutionalized when the Second International Conference of Labour Statisticians, convened by the International Labour Organization, promulgated the first international standards of measurement.”

Agrekon, Vol 43, No 2 (June 2004), Vink, Kirsten and Woermann.

The CPI is a non-monetary index number measuring changes in the weighted average of prices quoted in the functional currency of a typical basket of consumer goods and services. The per cent change in the CPI is used to measure inflation. It is a price index determined by measuring the price of a standard group of goods and services representing a typical market basket of a typical urban consumer. It measures the change in average price for a constant market basket of goods and services from one period to the next within the same area (city, region, or nation). It can be used to measure changes in the cost of living. It is a measure estimating the average price of consumer goods and services purchased by a typical urban household.

We use the change in the CPI as a measure to calculate the destruction of real value in monetary items (which cannot be indexed) and constant items never maintained (thus being treated as monetary items) over time in an inflationary economy implementing the HCA model. We also use the change in the CPI as a measure to calculate the creation of real value in monetary items (never indexed) and constant items never maintained (never decreased) over time in a deflationary economy. The CPI can be used to measure financial capital maintenance in units of constant purchasing power and thus index (adjust nominal values for inflation’s destruction of the real value of money which is the monetary unit of account) wages, salaries, pensions, all income statement items, issued share capital, retained profits, capital reserves, other shareholders´ equity items, trade debtors, trade creditors, taxes payable, taxes receivable and all other balance sheet constant items.

There is no CPI in a barter economy as there is no money in such an economy. The CPI is essential to maintain the real value of constant items in the economy with measurement of financial capital maintenance in units of constant purchasing power being used as the fundamental model of accounting. The CPI is used to calculate the destruction of real value in constant items never maintained in low inflationary economies using HCA as the fundamental model of accounting.

The real value of money is automatically updated by inflation and deflation. Whereas the price of a constant item should change inversely with the change in the real value of money, the real value of money changes inversely with the change in the level of the CPI.

The CPI is the sine qua non in an inflationary and deflationary economy for correcting the problem created by the fact that money is the only universal unit of account that is not a stable unit of measure. It would be impossible to measure inflation and deflation without the CPI. Consequently it would also have been impossible to stop the destruction of the real value in constant real value non-monetary items never maintained (generally retained profits and issued share capital of companies using HCA during inflation with no fixed assets or not sufficient fixed assets to maintain equity´s real value).

This massive destruction of the real value of SA companies´ and banks´ retained profits never maintained, unknowingly perpetrated by SA accountants implementing their very destructive stable measuring unit assumption during low inflation would have been impossible to stop without the CPI. The CPI makes it easy to fix the problem and to stop our accountants destroying about R200 billion each and every year in the SA real economy.

When our accountants freely start measuring financial capital maintenance in units of constant purchasing power as the IASB authorized them to do 20 years ago in the Framework, Par. 104 (a), then they will maintain all constant items in the SA economy for an unlimited period of time by updating them in terms of the change in the CPI instead of destroying their real values at a rate equal to the inflation rate as they are unknowingly doing right now. They would do that even in companies with no fixed assets at all. The "equivalent fixed assets requirement" is only applicable with the stable measuring unit assumption.

© 2005-2010 by Nicolaas J Smith. All rights reserved

No reproduction without permission.

Thursday, 15 October 2009

Money has no intrinsic value

Our money today has no intrinsic value in itself. It is fiat money that is created by government fiat or decree. The government declares fiat money to be legal tender. In the past monetary coins were made of, for example, silver or gold which were valuable in themselves. The actual metal of which the coin was made had a real or intrinsic value supposedly equivalent to the nominal value inscribed on the coin. Today fiat money is a government decreed and legally recognized medium of exchange, a unit of account and a store of value in our economy.

Our money today has no intrinsic value, as it is the natural product of the development of the monetary unit through time. In the beginning stages it was a full value metal coin. Later it was not a full value metal coin but it was the next best thing as far as economic agents were concerned: it was 100 per cent backed by gold. Today it has no intrinsic value and it is not backed by gold but is “backed” by the combined macroeconomic real value of all the underlying value systems in our economies. This includes, but is not limited to, the economic system, the manufacturing system, the industrial system, the monetary system, the political system, the social system, the educational system, the defence system, the health system, the security system, the legal system, the accounting system, and so on, to name but a few.

Money´s lack of intrinsic value is one of the reasons why gold is the best long-term hedge against economic and political meltdown.

Kindest regards,

Nicolaas Smith

Tuesday, 13 October 2009

SA accountants simply assume there is no inflation


SA accountants simply assume there is no such thing as inflation and never ever was before either.


Inflation is a rise in the general price level of goods and services in an economy over a period of time. When the general price level rises, each unit of currency buys fewer goods and services; consequently, inflation destroys the real value (purchasing power) of money.

The effect of inflation is distributed evenly in money and monetary items and as a consequence there are hidden costs to some and hidden benefits to others from this destruction in purchasing power in items that are assets to some while a the same time liabilities to others. For example, with inflation lenders or depositors who are paid a fixed rate of interest on loans or deposits will lose purchasing power from their interest earnings, while their borrowers will benefit. Individuals and institutions with net monetary assets will experience a net monetary loss (less real value owned/more real value – real assets – destroyed) while individuals and institutions with net monetary liabilities will experience a net monetary gain (less real value owed/more real liabilities destroyed) during inflation.

Increases in the price level (inflation) destroy the real value of money (the functional currency) and other monetary items with an underlying monetary nature (e.g. bonds and loans). However, inflation has no effect on the real value of variable real value non-monetary items (e.g. property, plant, equipment like cars, gold, inventories, finished goods, foreign exchange, etc) and constant real value non-monetary items (e.g. issued share capital, retained profits, capital reserves, other shareholder equity items, salaries, wages, rentals, pensions, trade debtors, trade creditors, taxes payable, taxes receivable, deferred tax assets, deferred tax liabilities, etc).

Inflation destroys the real value of money. Inflation has no effect on the real value of non-monetary items. Fixed constant real value non-monetary items never maintained are effectively treated like monetary items under traditional Historical Cost Accounting. Their real values are destroyed at a rate equal to the rate of inflation because they are measured in nominal monetary units and inflation destroys the real value of money which is the monetary unit of account.

SA accountants choose to implement the stable measuring unit assumption during low inflation when they value constant items in fixed nominal monetary units. Accountants´ choice of implementing the stable measuring unit assumption instead of measuring constant items´ real values in units of constant purchasing power, as they are authorized to do in the Framework, Par. 104 (a), results in the real values of these fixed constant items being destroyed at a rate equal to the rate of inflation when they are never maintained during low inflation because inflation destroys the real value of money which is the monetary unit of account. Fixed constant items never maintained are effectively monetary items under HCA. Their real values are destroyed at a rate equal to the rate of inflation because they are measured in nominal monetary units and inflation destroys the real value of money which is the monetary unit of account.

This costs the SA real economy about R200 billion per annum in unknowing real value destruction by SA accountants implementing their very destructive stable measuring unit assumption. They can freely stop this by measuring financial capital maintenance in units of constant purchasing power as they have been authorized to do by the IASB in 1989 in the Framework, Par. 104 (a) which states:

"Financial capital maintenance can be measured in either nominal monetary units or in units of constant purchasing power."

They refuse to do that.
The extremely rapid destruction of the real value of the monetary unit of account is compensated for during hyperinflation by the rejection of the stable measuring unit assumption in International Accounting Standard IAS 29 Financial Reporting in Hyperinflationary Economies. IAS 29, which has to be implemented during hyperinflation, requires all non-monetary items (variable items and constant items) to be measured in units of constant purchasing power.

© 2005-2010 by Nicolaas J Smith. All rights reserved

No reproduction without permission.

Monday, 12 October 2009

Net monetary gains and losses

Hi,

Net monetary gains and losses are calculated and accounted during hyperinflation as required by IAS 29 Financial Reporting in Hyperinflationary Economies and with the measurement of financial capital maintenance in units of constant purchasing power in terms of the IASB´s Framework, Par. 104 (a) during low inflation. Net monetary gains and losses are not required to be computed under the traditional Historical Cost Accounting model although it has been stated that it can be done.

Computing the gains or losses from holding monetary items can be done and the information disclosed when the books are maintained on a historical-cost basis.

Harvey Kapnick, Chairman of Arthur Anderson & Company, Value based accounting: Evolution or revolution, Saxe Lecture, 1976, Page 6.

http://newman.baruch.cuny.edu/DIGITAL/saxe/saxe_1975/kapnick_76.htm

This omission to compute the gains and losses from holding monetary items is a consequence of the stable measuring unit assumption.

The Measuring Unit principle: The unit of measure in accounting shall be the base money unit of the most relevant currency. This principle also assumes the unit of measure is stable; that is, changes in its general purchasing power are not considered sufficiently important to require adjustments to the basic financial statements.

Paul H. Walgenbach, Norman E. Dittrich and Ernest I. Hanson, (1973), Financial Accounting, New York: Harcourt Brace Javonovich, Inc. Page 429.

Kindest regards,

Nicolaas Smith

Money versus real value

In practice, money has a specific real value for a month at a time in an internal economy during low inflation. It changes every time the CPI changes. A monetary note or monetary coin has its nominal value permanently printed on it. Its nominal value does not and now cannot change.

Today monetary units are mostly created in economies subject to inflation. The Japanese economy is regularly in a state of deflation.

Money refers to a monetary unit used within the economy or monetary union in which it is created. This does not refer to the foreign exchange value of a monetary unit. The foreign exchange value of a monetary unit refers to its exchange value in relation to another monetary unit normally the monetary unit of another country or monetary region.

The real value of money would remain the same over time only at sustainable zero per cent annual inflation. Money would thus be the same as real value only at sustainable zero per cent annual inflation. This has never happened on a permanent basis in any economy. Now and then countries achieve zero inflation for a month or two at a time. But never for a sustainable period of a year or more.

Real value is the most important fundamental economic concept although it is the lesser studied and understood compared to the study of money. Money and real value are, unfortunately, not one and the same thing during inflation and deflation. Money and monetary items always have lower real values during inflation and higher real values during deflation under any accounting model.

Money is an invention. We can terminate its existence while real value is a fundamental economic concept, which exists, while we exist. Economies have already functioned without money. Barter economies operated without a medium of exchange. Cuba in the past bought oil from Venezuela and paid part in money and part by the provision of the services of sports coaches and medical doctors. Corn farmers in Argentina stored their corn in silos and paid for new pick-up trucks and other expensive mechanized farm implements with quantities of corn - the unit of real value Adam Smith described more than 220 years ago as a very stable unit of real value.

There will always be real value while the human race exists. The need for a medium of exchange, which is money’s first and basic function, is equally true. Money is one of the greatest human inventions of all time. It ranks on par with the invention of the wheel and the Gutenberg press in terms of importance to human development. Without money modern human development would have been very slow indeed.

Monetary items have the exact same attributes as money with the single exception that they are not actual bank notes and bank coins.

Non-monetary items are all items that are not monetary items.

Kindest regards,

Nicolaas Smith

Friday, 9 October 2009

Money illusion

Definition: Money illusion is the mistaken belief that money is stable – as in fixed – in real value over time.

Money illusion is primarily evident in low inflation countries. In hyperinflationary countries there is absolutely no money illusion as far as the hyperinflationary national currency is concerned. Everyone knows as a fact that the local hyperinflationary currency loses value day by day. In low inflationary countries people are vaguely aware that money loses value over a long period of time. Over the short term, however, low inflation money is used as if its real value is completely stable – as in fixed.

Money illusion is evident everywhere in low inflationary economies. TV channels reporting on historical events regularly quote historical values as the most natural thing to do. “Marble Arch was built for 10 000 Pounds” the TV reporter states with sincere knowledge that his audience is being well entertained with correct facts and figures. It is a figure very difficult to instantaneously value today. 10 000 British Pounds was the original cost in historical terms but we live today and absolutely no-one can immediately imagine what the construction cost of Marble Arch was in current terms. It is the same as saying that 300 years ago something cost one Pound. It is impossible to immediately value it now. We live now and not 300 years in the past. We don’t know what some-one could have bought for a Pound 300 years ago. People in the United Kingdom know what a person can buy for one Pound now – and that value changes month after month.

Companies report an unending stream of information about their performance and results. Sales increased by 5 per cent over last year’s figures, for example. Are these historical cost comparisons or real value comparisons? It is more never than hardly ever stated.

Money illusion is very, very common in our low inflationary economies. An example: The BBC recently ran a program about the fantastic E-Type Jag. It was stated that one of the many reasons why the E-type Jag - the best car ever, according to the presenter - was such a success was its original nominal price of 2 500 Pounds at the time of its first introduction into the market. Towards the end of the program it is then stated that a number of years later these same original E-Type Jags sold at a nominal price at that time of 25 000 Pounds. It is thus implied to be 10 times more than the original price of 2 500 Pounds. In nominal terms, yes. We all agree. Certainly not in real terms and we are interested in real values. We are real people. We live real lives in a real world. Nominal profits - however fantastic they may look - are misleading the longer the time period and the higher the rate of inflation or hyperinflation in the transaction currency during the time period involved.

In this example we are all led to believe that the E-Type Jag was sold at a real value 10 times its original real value. It is the notorious money illusion at work. The real value in a sale like that certainly would not be 10 times the original real value once the original nominal price is adjusted for inflation in the British Pound over the years in question.

Money illusion in Historical Cost values

(The following is adapted from a live-event on CNN. Any resemblance to a living person is purely coincidental ;-)

Let us assume a highly respected 75-year-old grandfather tries to encourage his grandson to accept a low starting salary in a very good company as a good starting point for the youngster’s career. The grandfather may mention that when he started work he earned 25 Dollars per week - meaning that he also started with a low salary and worked his way up. Stating his starting salary at its original historical cost value of maybe more than 50 odd years ago completely distorted the example he was trying to give. He was trying to say - and he certainly did, incorrectly (unintentional though it may have been) create the impression - that he started work at a low salary and had to work his way up. When the original historical cost value of 25 US Dollars of the grandfather’s first weekly pay packet is inflation-adjusted for inflation - in the medium of exchange - during the fifty or more years of his working life till the date of his comments on CNN, we find that he started work at a monthly salary of about 5 000 US Dollars current at the date of his comments. So, at 60 000 US Dollar per year the grandfather had a very good starting salary - which is exactly the opposite of what he was trying to say to his grandson.

That is money illusion at work. Money illusion is so pervasive in our low inflation societies that we do not even notice it any more. It is a complete state of mind - a way of thinking.

We have to stop thinking in money terms and start thinking in real value terms. As long as there is positive inflation in an economy, the national currency created and used in that inflationary economy is not a store of stable real value. It is a store of decreasing real value. Money is losing real value all the time when an economy is in a state of inflation. All current notes and coins will actually be worthless sometime in the future when an economy remains in an inflationary mode for a long enough period of time.

Money developed upon the mistaken belief that it is stable – as in fixed – in real value in the short to medium term in economies with low inflation. The term stable money is seen as meaning that money’s real value stays intact over the short to medium term in low inflationary economies. Money illusion is still very evident today in most economies in money, monetary items and constant items that are mistakenly considered to be monetary items, for example, trade debtors and trade creditors.

Kindest regards,

Nicolaas Smith

Thursday, 8 October 2009

International Financial Reporting Standards

Constant Item Purchasing Power Accounting is authorized by the IASB during low inflation

The statement that financial capital maintenance can be measured in either constant purchasing power units or in nominal monetary units in the IASB´s Framework, means that CIPPA has been authorized by the IASB since 1989 as an alternative to the traditional HCA model during periods of low inflation.

This means that the international accounting profession has been in agreement regarding the use of CIPPA for financial capital maintenance in units of constant purchasing power during low inflation since 1989. The standards thus reject the stable measuring unit in this option and in IAS29 Financial Reporting in Hyperinflationary Economies.

Income statement constant real value non-monetary items like salaries, wages, rentals, utilities, transport fees, etc are normally valued by accountants in terms of units of constant purchasing power during low inflation in most economies including South Africa.

Payments in money for these items are normally inflation-adjusted by means of the CPI to compensate for the destruction of the real value of the unstable monetary medium of exchange by inflation. Inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon and can only destroy the real value of money (the functional currency inside an economy) and other monetary items. Inflation can not and does not destroy the real value of non-monetary items.

© 2005-2010 by Nicolaas J Smith. All rights reserved

No reproduction without permission.

Wednesday, 7 October 2009

Real value destruction in the South African economy

There are two processes of economy wide real value destruction operating in the SA economy. The one overall real value destruction process is well known and generally accepted. It is inflation. Inflation is the enemy in the monetary economy and the Governor of the Reserve Bank is the enemy of inflation. Everybody knows that inflation is destroying the real value of their Rands and all other monetary items at the rate of 6.4% per annum, at the moment. Value date: August 2009 CPI 108.5

The second process of economy wide real value destruction is the unknowing, unintentional and completely unnecessary destruction by SA accountants of the real value of constant items never maintained in the SA constant item economy. This is the result of their implementation of the very destructive stable measuring unit assumption during low inflation as part of the real value destroying traditional Historical Cost Accounting model used by most SA companies. The enemy is SA accountants´ stable measuring unit assumption. In principle, they assume the unit of measure, the Rand, is perfectly stable during inflation; that is, they assume that changes in its general purchasing power are not sufficiently important to require the inflation-adjustment of the nominal values of all constant items in the SA economy in order to maintain their real values constant. In so doing, they unknowingly destroy the real values of constant items never maintained during inflation.

SA accountants´ stable measuring unit assumption is a stealth enemy: hardly anyone understands that when accountants implement it they are unknowingly and unintentionally responsible for the destruction of the real values of constant items not maintained under HCA during inflation.

Table 1: Real value destruction: Historical Cost Paradigm

Monetary aggregate: M3 R1 952.799 billion SARB: Value date: August 2009
Estimated value of constant items not maintained in SA economy: R 3 333 billion

Table 2: Real value destruction: Const. ITEM Purch. Power Accounting

Table 1 above gives us a close estimate of the state of real value destruction in the SA economy at the moment: In the 12 month period ending in August, 2009, inflation actually destroyed R1 952.799 billion x 0.064 = R124.9 billion in the real value of the Rand in the SA monetary economy. At the same time SA accountants unknowingly, unintentionally and completely unnecessarily destroyed about R200 billion in the real value of constant items never maintained in the SA constant item economy. About R324 billion in real value was thus destroyed in the SA economy in the 12 months to August, 2009 by inflation and by SA accountants implementing their very destructive stable measuring unit assumption.

If inflation stays at 6.4% for the next five years and SA accountants keep on unknowingly destroying the real values of constant items not maintained with their very destructive stable measuring unit assumption then a cumulative total of R1 620 billion in real value would be destroyed in the SA economy – all else being equal. The cumulative totals of real value destruction under these circumstances for 10, 20 and 30 years would be R3 240 billion, R6 480 billion and R9 720 billion respectively – ceteris paribus. These are huge values of real value destruction in the SA economy of which the part for which SA accountants are unknowingly responsible, is completely unnecessary and can easily be prevented.

We can see from Table 2 what the difference would be when SA accountants freely decide to measure financial capital maintenance in units of constant purchasing power as the IASB authorized them to do 20 years ago in the Framework, Par. 104 (a).

The destruction of real value in constant items would stop completely. There would only be real value destruction in the real value of the Rand because of inflation. At 6.4% annual inflation only R124 billion in real value would be destroyed in the economy as a whole instead of the current about R324 billion over a period of 12 months. Over five years the cumulative total of real value destruction would drop from R1 620 billion to R 624 billion, over 10 years from R3 240 billion to R1 249 billion, over 20 years from R6 480 billion to R2 498 billion and over 30 years from R9 720 billion to R3 747 billion.

SA accountants unknowingly destroy existing real values in existing constant items with their very destructive stable measuring unit assumption. When they stop their stable measuring unit assumption they would knowingly maintain about R200 billion in existing constant item real values during every period of 12 months in the SA real economy amounting to R1 000 billion over 5 years, R 2 000 billion over 10 years, R4 000 over 20 years and R6 000 billion over 30 years. Boosting the real economy with these real values would make a very big difference to the SA economy as a whole, to growth and to employment in the economy over that period.

Obviously a further reduction of inflation to an annual average of 3% would improve the SA economy even more. Over 30 years it would boost the economy by a further R2 000 billion on top of the R6 000 to be gained when SA accountants freely switch over to financial capital maintenance in units of constant purchasing power.

Kindest regards,

Nicolaas Smith

Tuesday, 6 October 2009

Capital illusion

Capital illusion is the mistaken belief by accountants, economists, analysts, investors and business people that the real value of companies´ capital and retained profits are always adequately maintained during low inflation under the Historical Cost paradigm.

Capital illusion is aided and abetted by the International Accounting Standards Board’s unqualified statement in the Framework, Par. 104 (a) that financial capital maintenance can be measured in nominal monetary units.

It is impossible to maintain the real value of financial capital in nominal monetary units – per se – during inflation.

100% of the inflation-adjusted original real values of all contributions to Shareholders´ Equity have to be invested during inflation in revaluable variable item fixed assets with an equivalent updated fair value (revalued or with unrecorded hidden holding gains) in order not to destroy Shareholders Equity’s original real value at a rate equal to the rate of inflation under the traditional Historical Cost Accounting model implemented by most companies in South Africa.

Very few companies in SA abide by the 100% of equity invested in fixed assets rule.

There is neither capital illusion nor massive unnecessary capital destruction when financial capital maintenance is measured in units of constant purchasing power as authorized by the IASB in the Framework, Par. 104 (a) in 1989: the real value of Shareholders´ Equity is maintained even without fixed assets in companies that break even.

Kindest regards,

Nicolaas Smith

Summary: Capital illusion is the mistake everyone makes in thinking that the real value of companies´ equity (capital and retained profits) is always backed by their fixed assets - either revalued or with unaccounted holding gains. Inflation-adjusting all constant items will maintain the real value of your equity forever as long as you break even - even if you have no fixed assets at all - instead of destroying the unbacked part at the rate of inflation as accountants are unknowingly doing at the moment, unnecessarily decapitalizing SA companies and banks by about R200 billion per year.

Monday, 5 October 2009

Mboweni´s R120 billion annual gift to South Africa

Money illusion is still very evident today in most economies in money, monetary items and constant items that are mistakenly considered to be monetary items, for example, trade debtors and trade creditors.

The incorrect treatment of trade debtors and trade creditors as monetary items is mainly due to the incorrect definition of monetary items in IFRS. IAS 29, Par. 12 defines monetary items incorrectly as follows:

Monetary items are money held and items to be received or paid in money.

Not all items to be received or paid in money are monetary items – per se. Money is simply used as the generally accepted medium of exchange to transfer monetary items as well as most non-monetary items from one economic entity to another. Most non-monetary items are transferred from one entity to another by generally accepted mutual agreement to use money as the medium of exchange.

Money has the legal backing of being legal tender. Legal tender is an offered payment that, by law, cannot be refused in settlement of a debt. Legal tender is anything which, when offered, extinguishes the debt. Credit cards, debit cards, personal cheques and similar non-cash methods of payment are not usually legal tender. The law does not relieve the debt until payment is accepted which explains the practice in some economies of making out receipts for most payments. Bank notes and coins are usually defined as legal tender.

Monetary items are incorrectly defined in IAS 21, Par. 8 too:

Monetary items are units of currency held and assets and liabilities to be received or paid in a fixed or determinable number of units of currency.

Not all assets and liabilities to be received or paid in a fixed or determinable number of units of currency are monetary items – per se.

The correct definition of monetary items:

Monetary items are money held and items with an underlying monetary nature.

Money illusion is the mistaken belief by people in general that money’s real value is maintained in the short to medium term in low inflationary economies. Central bank governors aid and abet money illusion by regularly stating in their monetary policy statements that they are “achieving and maintaining price stability.”

“The MPC remains fully committed to its mandate of achieving and maintaining price stability.”

TT Mboweni, Governor. 2009-06-25: Statement of the Monetary Policy Committee, SARB.

It is not always pointed out by governors of central banks that the “price stability” they mention, refers to their definition of “price stability”. Jean-Claude Trichet, the President of the European Central Bank, is a central bank governor who regularly mentions that 2% inflation is their definition of price stability. Absolute price stability is a year-on-year increase in the Consumer Price Index of zero per cent. The SARB´s definition of “price stability” “is for CPI inflation to be within the target range of 3 to 6 per cent on a continuous basis.”

The SARB would aid in reducing money illusion by stating:

The MPC remains fully committed to its mandate of achieving and maintaining the SARB´s chosen level of price stability which is for CPI inflation to be within the target range of 3 to 6 per cent on a continuous basis. Absolute price stability is a year-on-year increase in the CPI of zero per cent. Current 6.4% annual inflation destroyed about R124 billion of the real value of the Rand over the past 12 months to the end of August, 2009. A one per cent decrease in inflation would maintain about R19 billion per annum of real value in the SA monetary economy.

Tito Mboweni, the highly respected outgoing Governor of the SARB, has achieved the remarkable distinction of reducing the average annual destruction of the real value of the Rand by inflation by 50% during his 10 year tenure at the helm of South Africa’s central bank. In the 18 years before his arrival, average annual destruction of the real value of the Rand by inflation was 12 % or R240 billion per annum in August, 2009 CPI value terms – ceteris paribus. This means that Mr Mboweni and his excellent team at the SARB managed to maintain, on average, an extra R120 billion per annum in the SA monetary economy over the last 10 years. This annual R120 billion benefit to the SA economy will remain in place as long as average annual inflation stays at 6% or lower – all else being equal.

A further reduction of average annual inflation to 3% - the bottom level of the SA´s inflation target range – would maintain an additional R60 billion per annum in the SA monetary economy. That would bring the total real value maintained to R180 billion per annum compared to the R240 billion real value destroyed per annum during the last 18 years before Mr Mboweni´s arrival at the SARB.

Kindest regards,

Nicolaas Smith

Saturday, 3 October 2009

Money makes the world go round

Hi,

Monetary items are money held and items with an underlying monetary nature.

Money is the greatest economic invention of all time. Money did not exist and was not discovered. It was invented over a long period of time. Money is a monetary item which is used as a medium of exchange and serves at the same time as a store of value and as the monetary unit of account for the accounting of economic activity in a country or a monetary region like the Rand Common Monetary Area which includes South Africa, Namibia, Swaziland and Lesotho.

Money is a medium of exchange which is its main function. Without that function it can never be money. Money is the functional currency in an economy, i.e. the currency of the primary economic environment in which an economic entity operates. The historical development of money led it also to be used as the fundamental unit of measure to account the value of economic items. Money is the only universal unit of measure that is not a stable value. All other universal units of measure are fundamentally stable units of measure, e.g. inch, centimetre, ounce, gram, kilogram, pound, etc.

Historically money developed on the mistaken belief by people in general that it is stable – as in fixed – in real economic value in the short to medium term in economies with low cash inflation. Stable in this instance was seen as meaning that money kept its real value intact over the short to medium term in low inflationary economies. Money illusion is still very evident today in most economies in money, monetary items and constant items that are mistakenly considered to be monetary items, for example, trade debtors and trade creditors. There is no money illusion in hyperinflationary economies. People know that hyperinflation destroys the real value of money very quickly.

It is not what it appears to be

When we discuss, write about, talk about or analyze this monetary item described above, we call it money and describe it using the term money with the implicit assumption that this money we are dealing with is stable - as in fixed - in real economic value in our low inflationary economies. We thus assume at the same time that prices are more or less stable in low inflationary economies.

The term stable is normally accepted by the public at large to indicate a permanently fixed situation or position or state or price or value. A stable – as in fixed - price over time would be drawn as a horizontal line on a chart. A slowly increasing price over time would be drawn as a slightly rising line on a chart. A slowly decreasing value over time would be drawn as a slightly declining line on a chart. When we say production of a commodity is stable we accept that the absolute number of items being produced is not fluctuating but is at the same level all the time.

The term stable as used by economists, however, does not mean a fixed price or level, even though that is what the public in general thinks it means. The term stable in economics these days means slowly increasing or slowly decreasing – depending on what it is being applied to. The term price stability as used by economists today does not mean that prices in general stay the same, but that prices in general are rising slowly – which is, as we are all taught, the popular definition of inflation.

The term stable money as used by economists equally does not mean that the real value of national monetary units they are talking about stays the same in the economy – even though that is what the public in general thinks it means. What they mean with stable money is that the real value of a national monetary unit is slowly decreasing over time – which is, as we shall see, a much better – but not yet the best – definition of inflation.

When a central bank governor says that the central bank’s primary task or objective is price stability what she or he means is that the central bank would be fulfilling its primary task, in an economy with low levels of inflation, when prices in general are slowly rising over time (that well known definition of inflation again). The flip side of that statement is that the real value of national monetary units is slowly being destroyed by inflation over time – the best definition of inflation.

A central bank’s primary task being price stability is the same as saying a central bank’s main responsibility is ensuring that inflation is maintained at a very low level. This low level is now generally accepted in first world economies to be up to 2 percent per annum. We know that inflation is always and everywhere the destruction of real value in money and other monetary items over time. We also know that inflation has no effect on the real value of non-monetary items.

The maintenance of price stability thus means that the primary task of a central bank is to limit the destruction of real value in money and other monetary items by inflation to a maximum of 2 percent per annum within an economy or common monetary area. Two percent continuous inflation destroys the following percentages of real value over the time periods indicated:

Years....%
5.......10
10......18
16......28
20......33
30......45
35......51

We also know that accountants unknowingly destroy the real value of constant items never or not fully updated during inflation when they implement the very destructive stable measuring unit assumption as part of the real value destroying traditional Historical Cost Accounting model. Historical Cost accountants thus unknowingly destroy the same percentages stated above in the real value of constant items never updated during continuous “price stability” of 2% inflation per annum in low inflation first world economies.

Kindest regards,

Nicolaas Smith

Friday, 2 October 2009

Deloitte ignores capital

Deloitte, one of the Big Four accounting and auditing multi-nationals, also ignores the paragraphs in the Framework that deal with the concepts of capital, capital maintenance and the determination of profit or loss in their presentation of the Framework on their site IAS Plus as at 02/10/2009. Deloitte do not even mention one word in their presentation of the Framework about the fact that companies can measure financial capital maintenance in units of constant purchasing power.



This appears to be another example of the lack of understanding by accountants in general that an essential function of accounting is to maintain the real value of constant items at all levels of inflation and deflation which can only be achieved with the IASB approved CIPPA model in the Framework, Par. 104 (a) during low inflation and IAS 29 during hyperinflation.

http://www.iasplus.com/standard/framewk.htm

Similarly the paragraphs in the Framework dealing with the concepts of capital, the concepts of financial capital maintenance and units of constant purchasing power were also omitted from presentation of the Framework in the Wikipedia article on IFRS till they were added very recently. The whole of the Framework was summarized in the Wikipedia article, except those paragraphs.

The concept of financial capital maintenance in units of constant purchasing power during low inflation seems to have been correctly treated by the IASC Board twenty years ago – and then simply just ignored by everyone.

Kindest regards,

Nicolaas Smith

Thursday, 1 October 2009

This is not inflation accounting

Constant ITEM Purchasing Power Accounting, despite being approved by the IASB in the Framework twenty years ago, is completely ignored by accountants in non-hyperinflationary economies even though it would maintain instead of destroy the real values of not only all income statement constant items but also all balance sheet constant real value non-monetary items for an unlimited period of time during low inflation and deflation. CIPPA would stop SA accountants unknowingly destroying about R200 billion in the real value of constant items in the SA real economy each and every year. CIPPA would result in SA accountants knowingly boosting the SA real economy by at least R200 billion per annum for an unlimited period – ceteris paribus.

The reason accountants ignore CIPPA is because any price-level accounting model is generally viewed by almost all accountants and accounting authorities as a 1970-style failed and discredited inflation accounting model that requires all non-monetary items - variable real value non-monetary items and constant real value non-monetary items - to be inflation-adjusted by means of the CPI.

SA accountants forego the opportunity to implement the substantial real value maintaining benefits of measuring financial capital maintenance in units of constant purchasing power in SA companies and the economy in general. This results in the unknowing and unintentional destruction by SA accountants of billions of Rand in real value in the SA real economy – in most companies´ Retained Earnings (to name just one item unknowingly destroyed by SA accountants like this) - year in year out because they choose to measure financial capital maintenance in nominal monetary units and implement the very destructive stable measuring unit assumption as part of the real value destroying HCA model in SA when they maintain the stable measuring unit assumption for an unlimited period of time during indefinite inflation.

© 2005-2010 by Nicolaas J Smith. All rights reserved

No reproduction without permission