Pages

Monday, 14 January 2013

No guidance from the IASB to hyperinflationary countries


No guidance from the IASB to hyperinflationary countries

 

The replacement of the failed IAS 29 was not initially about the replacement of the failed IAS 29 restatement model; it was initially about when – at what level of annual or cumulative inflation – the failed IAS 29 restatement model has to be implemented as stated by the Chairman of the IASB, Mr Hans Hoogervorst, in the covering letter to the 2011 Agenda Consultation comment letter request.

 

The Argentinean Federation (supported by the Mexican, Chilean and Brazilian accounting standard-setting authorities) proposed the continued use of the failed IAS 29 restatement model at 10% annual inflation or at 26% cumulative inflation over three years instead of at 100% cumulative inflation over three years as required in the failed IAS 29. They proposed this in their draft IFRS ´X`INFLATION submitted to the IASB in 2010. I support a change from HCA at the above levels of inflation as proposed by the Argentinean Federation as I set out in my amendment to the Argentinean Federation´s proposal in which I changed the core principle and the name of the proposal from IFRS ´X`INFLATION to  IFRS ´X`CAPITAL MAINTENANCE IN UNITS OF CONSTANT PURCHASING POWER. In it I propose the adoption of the IFRS-authorised CMUCPP model instead of the failed IAS 29 restatement model. I am totally against the continuance of the failed IAS 29 restatement model which had no positive effect during its implementation during 8 years in Zimbabwe´s hyperinflation.

 

In my opinion, the future replacement of the failed IAS 29 is only now being researched correctly to determine:

 

(1)        Whether it is correct to implement a change in financial reporting at 10% annual inflation or at 26% cumulative inflation over three years as proposed in the Argentinean Accounting Federation´s proposal IFRS `X´ INFLATION instead of at 100% cumulative inflation over three years as required in the failed IAS 29 and

(2)        Whether the failed IAS 29 restatement model should be maintained in the future replacement of IAS 29 or whether it should be replaced with the IFRS-authorised Capital Maintenance in Units of Constant Puchasing Power in terms of a Daily Index model as proposed in the amended IFRS ´X`CAPITAL MAINTENANCE IN UNITS OF CONSTANT PURCHASING POWER.

 

I do realise that I may also be totally wrong in my assumption that the replacement of the failed IAS 29 now also includes the analysis of whether or not the failed replacement model should be replaced with the IFRS-authorised Capital Maintenance in Units of Constant Purchasing Power model. There is no official statement from the IASB to this effect. The IASB so far only indicated officially what its Chairman, Mr Hans Hoogervorst, stated in the 2011 Agenda Consultation comment letter request document: “Inflation accounting (revisions to IAS 29 Financial Reporting in Hyperinflationary Economies)

IAS 29 provides guidance on the preparation of financial statements in a functional currency that is suffering from hyperinflation. Concerns have been raised from some countries whose economies suffer from high inflation, but which are not hyperinflationary. Those concerns are that the effects of high inflation on an entity’s financial results are not adequately reflected in IFRS financial statements. A research paper was prepared on this issue and submitted to the IASB

by the Federación Argentina de Consejos Profesionales de Ciencias Económicas. A future project could use this research paper to consider revisions to IAS 29 to include guidance for entities whose functional currency is that of an economy subject to high inflation, but not to hyperinflation.”

 

The fact that I have sent an amendment to the Argentinean Federation´s proposal to the IASB in January 2012, does not mean that my proposal to change the core principle of the Argentinean Federation´s proposal from INFLATION to CAPITAL MAINTENANCE IN UNITS OF CONSTANT PURCHASING POWER was accepted by the IASB as a second valid reason for replacing the failed IAS 29. In my opinion, there seems to be very little understanding of the benefits of the IFRS-authorised CMUCPP in terms of a Daily Index model at the IASB.

 

During my collaboration with the IASB in my IFRIC agenda request I was informed, I assume unofficially, And with regard to the point on whether the IASB would accept the method written in the IFRS 'X', I would say that it won't be a short period of time to know if the IASB decides to use that concept. As you know, currently it is just a research project and therefore it is reasonable to expect the IASB to take a time to decide if it wants to add the project to the IASB's agenda. After that, it will decide what kind of model the IASB should explore.”


 

However, there is nothing official from the IASB regarding researching the future replacement of the failed IAS 29 with the view of replacing the failed restatement model as required in the failed IAS 29 with the IFRS-authorised CMUCPP model in terms of a Daily Index as proposed in the amendment IFRS `X´ CAPITAL MAINTENANCE IN UNITS OF CONSTANT PURCHASING POWER.

 

The last indication I had from the IASB was from what Micheal Stewart, the Director of Implementation Activities at the IASB, very firmly indicated during the teleconference on 8 January 2013, namely that the IASB is satified with the implementation of IAS 29  during 8 years in Zimbabwe´s hyperinflationary economy, because financial reporting has no effect in the economy. This statement from Michael Stewart is obviously totally wrong. That was his very firm response when I asked him what the IASB´s response was to the fact that IAS 29 had no positive effect during 8 years of implementation during Zimbabwe´s hyperinflation. According to him it is what people do with the information in financial reports that affects the economy.

 

View that financial reporting has no effect in the economy may be widely held at the IASB

 

In my opinion, the IASB has a very irresponsible attitude to the fact that the implementation of IFRS-authorised Capital Maintenance in Units of Constant Purchasing Power in terms of a Daily Index in the current hyperinflationary economies of Belarus, Venezuela and Iran would stabilise these countries´ economies. In my opinion, this may be because the view that financial reporting has no effect in the economy may be widely held at the IASB: it may not be generally accepted or realised (understood) at the IASB that financial reporting affects the economy (see Michael Stewart´s very firm indication in this regard) and that the implementation of CMUCPP in terms of a Daily Index – as authorised in IFRS in 1989 – would very quickly stabilise the hyperinflationary economies in Belarus, Venezuela and Iran.

 

This is only my private opinion: I may be wrong. Maybe the IASB does realise that CMUCPP in terms of a Daily Index – as authorised in IFRS in 1989 – would stabilise the above hyperinflationary economies very quickly and are about the put the replacement of the failed IAS 29 on a fast track.

 

On the other hand, I doubt this very much especially when Michael Stewart indicated very firmly that financial reporting has no effect in the economy: a totally wrong – and very worrying - indication. I thus have little hope for guidance from the IASB for the accountants in the above hyperinflationary countries. An IFRS requiring CMUCPP in terms of a Daily Index during hyperinflation – CMUCPP was authorised in IFRS as an option to HCA in 1989 at all levels of inflation and deflation, including during hyperinflation - would stabilise these countries´ economies overnight at no cost. In my opinion, the IASB does not demonstrate the necessary understanding of the real value maintaining benefits of CMUCPP in terms of a Daily Index during hyperinflation to authorise such an IFRS and to provide such guidance. So, in my opinion, concluding from what I have stated before, the IASB would, most probably, also not be able to sufficiently understand (similar to what I personally experienced with the two IASB staff members in my collaboration with them during my IFRIC agenda request) the real value maintaining benefits of IFRS-authorised Capital Maintenance in Units of Constant Purchasing Power in terms of a Daily Index, to put the replacement of the failed IAS 29 on a fast track. In my opinion, Michael Stewart will certainly not be able to convey the real value maintaining benefits of IFRS-authorised CMUCPP in terms of a Daily Index to the IASB. In my opinion, he does not understand those benefits and he would not be able to describe those benefits in detail nor the reason why IFRS-authorised CMUCPP in terms of a Daily Index affects the economy very positively. According to him financial reporting has no effect in the economy: in my opinion, a totally wrong understanding of financial reporting.  That is very unfortunate for the populations of Belarus, Venezuela and Iran and the populations of all high inflationary countries in the world economy.

 

The benefits of CMUCPP in terms of a daily index was instinctively understood and widely implemented in Brazil during very high and hyperinflation from 1964 to 1994: it was widespread. It was also implemented instinctively and widely understood in Chile from 1967 to 2010 (mostly during low inflation) and in other Latin American countries: it was widespread in Latin America. Latin American countries seem to have understood it instinctively and applied it widely during low inflation, very high and hyperinflation.

 

The IASB, at best, could actively assist, like IASB staff actively assisted the Argentinean Federation in the preparation of their 2010 proposal, the national accounting standard-setting authorities in the above hyperinflationary countries to rapidly authorise national accounting standards requiring IFRS-authorised Capital Maintenance in Units of Constant Purchasing Power in terms of a Daily Index in order to stabilise these countries´economies – before the requirement by the IASB of IFRS-authorised CMUCPP in the replacement of the failed IAS 29.

 

With respect to both

 

(1)        the preparation of the IFRIC agenda request, namely: to include in IFRIC that “IAS 29 is not required during hyperinflation when an entity implements CMUCPP because this model is not a HCA model and only HC and CC financial statements are restated as required in IAS 29”, being directed by Michael Stewart, as well as

(2)        the future work (as detailed above) on the replacement of the failed IAS 29,

 

it is important to acknowledge that it is a fact that financial reporting affects the economy – and that it is not what Michael Stewart very firmly indicated, namely that financial reporting has no effect in the economy.
 




Nicolaas Smith

Copyright (c) 2005-2012 Nicolaas J Smith. All rights reserved. No reproduction without permission.

No comments:

Post a Comment